Saturday, August 29, 2009

The Failure of the Economy & the Economists

By now there are few people who do not acknowledge that the major American financial institutions and the markets they dominate turn out to have served the country badly in recent years. The surface evidence of this failure is the enormous losses—more than $4 trillion on the latest estimate from the International Monetary Fund—that banks and other lenders have suffered on their mortgage-related investments, together with the consequent need for the taxpayers to put up still larger sums in direct subsidies and guarantees to keep these firms from failing. With nearly 9 percent of the labor force now unemployed and still more joining their ranks, industrial production off by 13 percent compared to a year ago, and most companies' profits either falling rapidly or morphing into losses, it is also evident that the financial failure has imposed huge economic costs.

The government has moved aggressively, and on several fronts, to stanch the immediate damage. The Federal Reserve has not only eased monetary policy to the point of near-zero short-term interest rates but created a profusion of new programs to extend credit to banks as well as other lenders. Congress, at the Obama administration's behest, has enacted nearly $800 billion of new spending and tax cuts aimed at stimulating business and consumer spending. First the Bush administration and now Mr. Obama's have experimented with one new plan after another to rescue lenders and reliquify collapsed credit markets.
NYRB Summer Sale!

But despite the universal agreement that no one wants any more such failures once this one has passed, there is a troubling lack of attention to reforms that might prevent such a crisis from recurring. By now everyone realizes that excessive risk-taking, systematic mispricing of assets, and, often, plain reckless behavior (not to mention some instances of criminality, although to date surprisingly few of these have come to light) helped cause the current mess. At the same time, most people recognize both that parts of the American economy have been capable of dynamic growth and that the US financial markets have had a part in promoting that growth. The result is a reluctance to consider changes to the current system. Substantial interference with financial markets, it is said, amounts in the end to centrally planned allocation of an economy's investment process, and will result in technological stagnation and wasted resources. Milder attempts at regulation will either prove ineffective—the private sector can afford better lawyers than the government can—or at best merely lead financial institutions to relocate to more lightly regulated jurisdictions like the Cayman Islands.

As in past financial declines, what is sorely missing in this discussion is attention to what function the financial system is supposed to perform in the economy and how well it has been doing it. Today attention is mostly focused on banks' and other investors' losses from buying mortgage-backed securities at inflated prices. What is neglected is the consequence: if the prices of the securities were too high, this meant that the underlying mortgage rates were too low, and so too many houses were built, and too many Americans bought them. In just the same way, when the 1990s stock market boom crashed, everyone talked about investors' losses on their telecom stocks, not the fact that if the stocks' prices were too high, the cost of capital to the firms that issued the stocks was too low, and so communications companies laid millions of miles of fiber-optic cable that nobody ended up using.

In both instances, the cost was not just financial losses but wasted real resources. True, over longer periods of time the American financial system has seemed reasonably effective at allocating resources rather than wasting them. The economy's pace of technological advance and growth in production since World War II suggest that the banks and the stock and bond markets can steer investment capital reasonably effectively to firms that will use it productively, often including start-ups trying out a wholly new idea—Microsoft, or Google, or, earlier on, Apple. But the effectiveness of the economy's mechanism for allocating capital should be a matter for serious quantitative evaluation, not a matter of faith.

Moreover, to ask just how efficient a financial system is in allocating capital leads naturally to the question of the price that is paid for such efficiency. In recent years the financial industry has accounted for an unusually large share of all profits earned in the US economy. The share of the "finance" sector in total corporate profits rose from 10 percent on average from the 1950s through the 1980s, to 22 percent in the 1990s, and an astonishing 34 percent in the first half of this decade.[1]

Those profits accruing to the financial sector are part of what the economy pays for the mechanism that allocates its investment capital (as well as providing other services, like checking accounts and savings deposits). But even a stripped-down version of the cost of running the financial system includes not just the profits that financial firms earn but also the salaries, the office rents, the travel budgets, the advertising fees, and all of the other expenses they pay. The finance industry's share of US wages and salaries has likewise been rising, from 3 percent in the early 1950s to 7 percent in the current decade.[2] An important question—which no one seems interested in addressing—is what fraction of the economy's total returns to productively invested capital is absorbed up front by the financial industry as the costs of allocating that capital.

Further, the latest financial crisis is a sharp reminder that the simple operating expense of running the financial system—including profits of financial firms—is not the only cost if this system also exposes the economy at large to episodic losses in production and incomes, and to the need for taxpayer subsidies. Today those losses are mounting, and so are the subsidies. Many US banks, including some of the largest ones, are now insolvent. The bank rescue plans offered to date by both the Bush and the Obama administrations amount to ever more expensive fig leafs for avoiding concrete recognition of this sad development.

In the same effort, the Financial Accounting Standards Board—the independent organization designated by the SEC to set accounting standards—acting at the strong urging of Congress, recently changed its rules to allow banks more latitude to claim that assets on their balance sheets are worth more than what anyone is willing to pay for them. (Next time you apply for a loan, try mentioning FAS 157-4 and telling your banker that you should be allowed to calculate your net worth with your house priced not at what comparable houses are selling for now but at what you paid for it and what you hope you'll get for it if you hold on to it for some years. The banker will laugh, even while the bank applies just such standards to its own balance sheet.)

Another fundamental issue that the current discussion has overlooked almost entirely is the distinction between the losses to banks and other lenders that reflect genuine losses of wealth to the economy, and other losses that don't. When the value of your house falls, that's a loss of wealth to the economy as a whole. If you keep paying your mortgage, you bear the loss yourself: your net worth is diminished by the amount of the decline in the home's price. If you default on your loan, then someone else—maybe the bank that lent you the money, maybe some investor to whom the bank sold the loan—also bears part of the loss. If the government steps in and reimburses the bank, or the investor, the taxpayers will bear part of the loss as well. But however this loss is divided, what is inescapable is that someone, somewhere, will bear it. What much of today's debate is about is how these losses should be divided among homeowners, banks, loan-purchasing investors, and the taxpayers. But the loss must be borne by someone, and America's economy is poorer because it has occurred.

By contrast, suppose you and your neighbor have bet on whether today's peak temperature would exceed fifty degrees. One of you was right, the other wrong. One of you won, the other lost, and the amount the winner won is identical to what the loser lost. There is no loss of wealth to the economy, merely a transfer of wealth from the loser to the winner. Many of the huge losses that American financial institutions have sustained in the current crisis are of this second kind. None of them was betting on the weather, but they were taking positions that amounted to placing bets on outcomes that represented no change in wealth to the economy as a whole. And with regard to these positions, for every loser featured in the latest newspaper story about banks posting losses and turning to the government for bailouts there is also, somewhere, a winner.

The most telling example, and the most important in accounting for today's financial crisis, is the market for credit default swaps. A CDS is, in effect, a bet on whether a specific company will default on its debt. This may sound like a form of insurance that also helps spread actual losses of wealth. If a business goes bankrupt, the loss of what used to be its value as a going concern is borne not just by its stockholders but by its creditors too. If some of those creditors have bought a CDS to protect themselves, the covered portion of their loss is borne by whoever issued the swap.

But what makes credit default swaps like betting on the temperature is that, in the case of many if not most of these contracts, the volume of swaps outstanding far exceeds the amount of debt the specified company owes. Most of these swaps therefore have nothing to do with allocating genuine losses of wealth. Instead, they are creating additional losses for whoever bet incorrectly, exactly matched by gains for the corresponding winners. And, ironically, if those firms that bet incorrectly fail to pay what they owe—as would have happened if the government had not bailed out the insurance company AIG—the consequences might impose billions of dollars' worth of economic costs that would not have occurred otherwise.

This fundamental distinction, between sharing in losses to the economy and simply being on the losing side of a bet, should surely matter for today's immediate question of which insolvent institutions to rescue and which to let fail. The same distinction also has implications for how to reform the regulation of our financial markets once the current crisis is past. For example, there is a clear case for barring institutions that might be eligible for government bailouts—including not just banks but insurance companies like AIG—from making such bets in the future. It is hard to see why they should be able to count on taxpayers' money if they have bet the wrong way. But here as well, no one seems to be paying attention.

Why has there been so little discussion of fundamental issues like this distinction among losses? Why is so little said about the trade-off between the goal of allocating the economy's capital efficiently and the need to shrink the enormous costs of the financial industry in doing so? One obvious reason is political. There is a long arc from Roosevelt's acceptance of a useful role for government institutions and government regulation to the conviction of Reagan and Thatcher that the government is never the solution but actually the problem. A second, closely related reason is ideological: the faith, personified by Alan Greenspan with his early dedication to the writings of Ayn Rand and his staunch opposition to regulations while chairman of the Federal Reserve, that private, profit-driven economic activity is self-regulating and, when necessary, self-correcting.

The economists George Akerlof and Robert Shiller suggest a third reason. In their view, the problem is also intellectual—a systematic failure of thinking on the part of their fellow economists. Taking the title of their new book from a phrase famously used by John Maynard Keynes, Akerlof and Shiller argue that what is missing in the worldview of today's economists is sufficient attention to "animal spirits," by which they mean the psychological and even irrational elements that figure importantly in so many other familiar aspects of personal choices and personal behavior, and that, they believe, pervade economic behavior too.

Akerlof and Shiller identify five distinct elements in what they call "animal spirits": confidence, or the lack of it; concern for fairness, that is, for how people think they and others should behave—for example, that a hardware store shouldn't raise the price of snow shovels after a blizzard despite the increased demand; corruption and other tendencies toward antisocial behavior; "money illusion," meaning susceptibility to being misled by purely nominal price movements that, because of inflation or deflation, do not correspond to real values; and reliance on "stories"—for example, inspirational accounts of how the Internet led to a "new era" of productivity. The omission of these five aspects of "animal spirits," they argue, blocks conventional economics from either understanding today's crisis or providing useful ideas for dealing with it.

Most of Animal Spirits consists of surveys of disparate research programs in which either Akerlof or Shiller or both have participated—in many cases, led the way—demonstrating that the conventional economic models fail to fit the facts of one or another aspect of observable economic behavior. The topics they cover include (among others) joblessness, saving, the volatile prices of financial assets and of real estate, and the prevalence of poverty among African-Americans. Akerlof, a professor at Berkeley who deservedly won the Nobel Prize in 2001, and Shiller, a Yale professor who in time should do likewise, are both outstanding economists, and the work they review in each of these areas of research is of high quality. In this respect, their book is similar to recent offerings by other scholars that have also presented for a broader audience many of the findings of what has come to be known as "behavioral economics."[3]

Akerlof and Shiller, however, want Animal Spirits to do more than summarize distinct findings and their separate implications for policy. They see the limitations of today's conventional macroeconomics as systemic: "the theories economists typically put forth about how the economy works are too simplistic. That means we should fire the weather forecaster." And "firing the forecaster means giving up the myth that capitalism is purely good."

In an intuitively appealing illustration, Akerlof and Shiller suggest how to think about what's included and what's not in conventional economic theory, and what they intend their book to accomplish:

Picture a square divided into four boxes, denoting motives that are economic or noneconomic and responses that are rational or irrational. The current model fills only the upper left-hand box; it answers the question: How does the economy behave if people only have economic motives, and if they respond to them rationally? But that leads immediately to three more questions, corresponding to the three blank boxes.... We believe that the answers to the most important questions regarding how the macroeconomy behaves and what we ought to do when it misbehaves lie largely (though not exclusively) within those three blank boxes.

One of the inevitable difficulties with this kind of argument is that it depends so much on just how words are used. What is the difference between an economic and a noneconomic motive? If I buy a new car because I like its styling and good gas mileage, that's presumably an economic motive. What if it's a hybrid and part of my reason for buying it is that I value the "story" of my doing my bit to help slow global warming? If a business owner provides scholarships for his employees' children, is his motive to treat them fairly for fairness' sake or to foster their loyalty and thereby improve their productivity?

The answer, in the end, is that an "economic" motive is whatever economists include in their theories of how people behave. And since different economists are always proposing different theories, what constitutes an "economic" motive can differ from one theory, and one economist, to another. Since at any particular time there are dominant theories, there is some coherence to what people would understand as an "economic" motive; and so the point Akerlof and Shiller are trying to make here is far from empty. But it is more elusive than they suggest. The distinction between what's "rational" and what's not is, if anything, even more fraught.

Sometimes, moreover, Akerlof and Shiller's substantive arguments fall victim to a similar circularity. The element of animal spirits on which they place the most emphasis in their account of the current crisis is confidence. It is, they say, "the first and most crucial of our animal spirits." Is it rational or not for me to put my money in a bank in which I have confidence? Or to buy a stock if I have confidence in the company's business prospects? According to Akerlof and Shiller, this kind of behavior is, by definition, irrational since "confidence" for them is a kind of faith, not a matter of rational analysis: "The very term confidence...impl[ies] behavior that goes beyond a rational approach to decision making." (Similarly, when confidence is explained in terms of trust, "the very meaning of trust is that we go beyond the rational.")

This tendency to argue by definition also sometimes affects questions beyond whether something is to be classified as economic or noneconomic, or rational or irrational. One of the reasons confidence is so important in Akerlof and Shiller's list of animal spirits is that when people have too much of it, they behave in ways that cause the economy to become overheated. But this argument, too, turns out to be a matter of definition: "The term overheated economy, as we shall use it, refers to a situation in which confidence has gone beyond normal bounds...."

Concerns like these aside, the broader question is whether Akerlof and Shiller succeed in making more of the different kinds of research they report on in Animal Spirits than the sum of the book's disparate parts. The answer is yes in some respects, no in others.

They succeed in demonstrating both the narrowness of mainstream macroeconomic thinking in recent decades and the stranglehold that this thinking has placed on the economics profession's ability either to explain phenomena like today's crisis or to advance potential solutions. For example, economics today is largely taught using mathematical models to describe outcomes under different conditions. And for purposes of macroeconomics—the study of the economy as a whole—most of the standard models do not admit the possibility of unemployment. The reason is not that no one knows unemployment exists. Rather, no one has figured out how to allow for it within the confines of sufficiently simple mathematics; and faced with the choice between excluding unemployment and sacrificing analytical simplicity, most macroeconomists have opted for the former.

To point to another example even more central to what is happening currently, the standard macroeconomic analysis today also does not acknowledge the existence of banking or other kinds of borrowing and lending. Instructive models of credit markets are certainly available.[4] But incorporating them within the standard macroeconomic models would place too much strain on mathematical simplicity.

Akerlof and Shiller succeed, too, in demonstrating that conventional macroeconomic analyses often fail because they omit not just readily observable facts like unemployment and institutions such as credit markets but also harder-to-document behavioral patterns that fall within the authors' notion of "animal spirits." Confidence plainly matters, and so does the absence of it. When the public mood swings from exuberance to anxiety, or even fear, the effect on asset prices as well as on economic activity outside the financial sector can be large.

As they argue, these effects can plausibly be larger than the fluctuations attributable to more concrete factors, such as monetary policy or oil prices, that economists more typically incorporate in their analysis. Money illusion, by which people are influenced by purely nominal price movements, is also clearly important to some aspects of how the economy in aggregate behaves. (As they show, concerns for fairness, tendencies toward corruption, and reliance on "stories" also influence some aspects of economic behavior, but whether they are significant for the aggregate economy remains unclear.) "It is necessary," they argue,

to incorporate animal spirits into macroeconomic theory in order to know how the economy really works. In this respect the macroeconomics of the past thirty years has gone in the wrong direction.

The effort to "clean up macroeconomics and make it more scientific," to impose "research structure and discipline," has proved disastrously confining.

But what then? Is there more to Animal Spirits than a list of important influences for economists to try to take into account? Akerlof and Shiller believe they have proposed a new model for macroeconomic analysis. Comparing their work to Keynes's discussion of animal spirits from the 1930s, they write:

This book...describes how the economy really works.... With the advantage of over seventy years of research in the social sciences, we can develop the role of animal spirits in macroeconomics in a way that the early Keynesians could not. And because we acknowledge the importance of animal spirits, and accord them a central place in our theory rather than sweep them under the rug, this theory is not vulnerable to attack.

There are two problems here. One is simply the familiar tendency to overstate, especially when writing about one's own work. It is hard to believe that Akerlof and Shiller really see their ideas as invulnerable to attack. Similarly, after listing at the outset the subjects about which they will summarize the research that they and other scholars have done—e.g., "Why do economies fall into depression?"—they declare that "animal spirits provide an easy answer to each of these questions." The answers they summarize may be right or not (I vote yes) and they may be well argued or not, but they are not "easy."

The more important question is whether what Akerlof and Shiller have offered in Animal Spirits amounts to "a theory" in the sense that it could stand in place of the current theories that they criticize for being based entirely on rational responses to economic motives. There is a difference between a series of ideas about different aspects of economic behavior and an integrated account of macroeconomic fluctuations. Akerlof and Shiller are surely on the right track in pointing to elements that are missing from today's conventional models, and in arguing that incorporating them into mainstream macroeconomic analysis would help. But they have neither done this nor shown others how to. Hence their goal of replacing what macroeconomists teach their students is likely to be disappointed, at least for now.

And because what they have here is a set of examples of how "animal spirits" matter for specific aspects of economic behavior, not a coherently worked out theory of how the macroeconomy behaves, it is not surprising that Animal Spirits is also thin on suggestions for what to do about the current crisis. Akerlof and Shiller mostly restrict their recommendations to how economists should think, not what policymakers should do. The one concrete proposal they offer is that the government should have a target for the expansion of credit—that is, for the amount of borrowing and lending in the economy, presumably defined in some measurable way.

This idea has considerable merit (some years ago I wrote a series of papers advocating it myself[5]). But it is hard to see how it would help address the problems our economy faces today. Everyone knows that a principal objective of the Treasury's bank bailouts, the Federal Reserve's numerous new facilities for credit, the government's takeover of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, as well as other actions, is to restore the functioning of the credit markets so that borrowers can again obtain financing. It is not clear how stating a specific target for credit expansion would help further that goal. It is also not clear that the proposal follows, in any direct way, from the importance of animal spirits in influencing economic behavior.

What else? The "world of animal spirits gives the government an opportunity to step in," Akerlof and Shiller write. But in what ways? Apart from a target for credit growth, they mostly leave it at that. "This book cannot give the detailed answers" to current policy questions, they write. This is a pity. Because they are so convincing in their critique of modern macroeconomics, and because they point to the current crisis as a prime example of why this matters, readers will understandably want to know what policies they would recommend.

In his recent book The Subprime Solution, Shiller offered a series of proposals, recommending, for example, a new version of the Home Owners' Loan Corporation. which operated from 1933 to 1936 and provided generous subsidies for home mortgages, insisting, however, that they be paid off by steady monthly payments. He also advocated expanded financial disclosure requirements, greater availability of financial data, and a new government agency like the Consumer Product Safety Commission that could protect consumers by informing them about the safety of financial products.

Shiller made more far-reaching suggestions as well, proposing markets in which families could insure the risk inherent in owning their house[6] or earning their livelihood, and even a new way of expressing prices in a unit of account that would adjust for inflation or deflation, so as to help people overcome money illusion. Here he anticipated the discussion of "animal spirits" in his book with Akerlof:

The subprime crisis was essentially psychological in origin.... Denying the importance of psychology and other social sciences for financial theory would be analogous to physicists denying the importance of friction in the application of Newtonian mechanics.

But The Subprime Solution was (by intent) mostly focused on mortgages and the fallout from the subprime collapse. In Animal Spirits, Akerlof and Shiller make a much broader argument, but they say little about its concrete implications for macroeconomic policies: How much and what kind of fiscal stimulus is desirable now? What should be the role for monetary policy now that short-term interest rates are near zero? What changes should be made in financial regulation once the crisis is past?

Some of the proposals for regulatory reform now being put forward by others appear at least to connect to parts of Akerlof and Shiller's discussion. For example, they call attention to the potential instability inherent in the "new shadow banking system"—that is, institutions such as investment banks and even the off-balance-sheet entities sponsored by the banks themselves that now carry out many of the lending functions of banks but are not regulated as such and whose obligations are not ordinarily insured. They observe, correctly, that "there can be a 'run' on these institutions just as there can be a run on traditional banks." They are right; what happened last year to Bear Stearns and Lehman was, in effect, a run on a nonbank.

But what, then, should be done to prevent more such runs? Some ideas now under discussion include stronger accounting rules and wider capital requirements, so that hedge funds and insurance companies and other nonbanks too would have to hold capital against their risk positions. There is also support for empowering the government to take "prompt corrective action" to force nonbanks to address problems in their balance sheets, or if necessary take them into receivership, just as it already can with banks. A more controversial idea is to reinstitute some form of the Glass-Steagall Act that, until Congress repealed it in 1999, barred commercial banks from also doing investment banking. The Obama administration has proposed a new financial "super-regulator." How do animal spirits bear specifically on any of these issues? Akerlof and Shiller do not say.

But their silence on these and other policy issues and their lack of a full-blown "theory" to replace the strait-jacketed macroeconomics of the past few decades do not undercut the force of Akerlof and Shiller's central argument. Their harsh judgment of current mainstream macroeconomic thinking is true, and they are right about the importance of what they call "animal spirits" to many of its crippling shortcomings. Animal Spirits provides an agenda for new thinking, and one well worth pursuing.

—April 30, 2009
Notes

[1]Data are from the US Department of Commerce. "Finance" here excludes both insurance and real estate; with those additional firms included, the share of total profits in 2001–2005 was 37 percent.

[2]Thomas Philippon and Ariell Reshef, "Skill Biased Financial Development: Education, Wages and Occupations in the US Financial Sector," National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 13437, September 2007.

[3]See, for example, Richard H. Thaler and Cass R. Sunstein, Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth and Happiness (Yale University Press, 2008), reviewed in these pages by John Cassidy, June 12, 2008.

[4]Interestingly, many of Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke's most important contributions as an academic economist were models for analyzing the role of credit markets, including ways in which a falling value of either lenders' capital or borrowers' collateral can depress lending and therefore economic activity. See, for example, Bernanke and Alan S. Blinder, "Money, Credit and Aggregate Demand," The American Economic Review, May 1988; and Bernanke and Mark Gertler, "Agency Costs, Net Worth and Business Fluctuations," The American Economic Review, March 1989.

[5]See, for example, "Monetary Policy with a Credit Aggregate Target," Journal of Monetary Economics, Spring 1983 Supplement.

[6]The market for futures based on either nationwide or city-specific house price indexes, which Shiller helped to establish on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange, is a practical step in that direction.
By Benjamin M. Friedman

Thursday, August 27, 2009

It’s Hard to Worry About a Deficit 10 Years Out

Ten years ago, Washington was worried about the budget outlook, and there were forecasts of dire outcomes. And so it is today.

The difference is the nature of the worries. Alan Greenspan, then the Federal Reserve chairman, talked about the dangers of a shortage of Treasury securities as the $5 trillion surplus forecast for the next decade enabled the national debt to be paid down. This week we were warned of a $9 trillion deficit over the next 10 years.

“The last time people got really excited about a 10-year budget outlook, they were hysterically wrong about what transpired,” said Robert Barbera, the chief economist of ITG, who mocked the surplus forecasts then and now thinks the consensus outlook is too negative.

“The $5 trillion surplus was a ‘nothing can go wrong’ forecast,” he said. “No recessions, no wars, no bear markets and a perpetuation of inexplicably high tax receipts. You can make the case that the current conversations about our fiscal outlook are effectively, ‘Nothing can go right.’ The estimates assume we continue to allocate over $100 billion a year for fighting wars. They assume a very mild recovery for the economy, and an even milder recovery for tax receipts.”

It was easier a decade ago to know the forecast was foolish, although few did. The assumption that politicians would refrain from cutting taxes or raising spending in the face of large surpluses had no historical support.

On the other hand, the notion that politicians will point fingers and do nothing as deficits mount has plenty of historical support.

One unusual factor now is that everyone agrees Congress must pass a new tax law. If it does not, taxes on nearly everyone will soar under an absurd plan enacted in 2001 called the snap-back tax, which provides that in 2011 the tax law that had been in effect in 2000 will reappear.

That would drive tax rates up sharply for most people, which might reduce budget deficits. But it is hardly what anyone wants if the economy is not booming by then.

Most of the tax changes being mulled can await Congressional action until next year. Under the snap-back tax plan, however, the estate tax is set to vanish for a year if nothing happens before the end of 2009, just over four months from now.

Heirs of a very rich person who died on Dec. 31, 2010, would get everything, without any estate tax. If that person died a day later, his or her estate would owe 55 percent of everything over $1 million. (I call that the Dr. Kevorkian provision, after the physician who specialized in assisted suicides until he was sent to prison.) How will hospitals respond if heirs demand that life support be ended before the clock strikes 12?

It would have been nice to fix that up in a nonelection year, but the health care debate has consumed Congress. The chairman of one tax-writing committee, Senator Max Baucus, is still trying to shape a bipartisan health care bill, a Sisyphean task that may not leave much time for taxes. The other chairman, Representative Charles Rangel, has just discovered that he forgot to mention a checking account with more than $250,000 in it when he listed his assets. Tax policy may not be on the top of his to-do list either, at least while the dual investigations of his ethics are continuing.

The country got into the current tax mess because George W. Bush wanted it all in 2001. He could overcome procedural hurdles in the Senate and make the 10-year cost of his tax cut appear lower, if the entire bill was labeled temporary. So it was.

To make things worse, that bill did nothing about the alternative minimum tax, which was supposed to catch wealthy citizens with big deductions and force them to pay something. By not lowering the A.M.T. rates when ordinary tax rates were cut, the law negated the cuts for millions of middle-class people. Now Congress passes a temporary fix every year to keep that from happening. President Obama wants to make that fix permanent, something Mr. Bush was hesitant to do because it would have made deficit forecasts look worse.

When Congress does get around to tax law, the political calculations could be fun to watch. Read the numbers one way, and President Obama’s proposals call for big increases in taxes on every group. Read them another way, they call for tax cuts for every group except the most prosperous one-tenth of 1 percent of Americans. Guess which interpretation the Republicans, and the Democrats, will choose.

The numbers to back each interpretation come from a new study by the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center, estimating effective federal tax rates using both current law and President Obama’s legislative proposals. The figures include all federal taxes, allocating corporate taxes to the owners of those companies and payroll taxes to the employees. Middle-income people tend to pay higher payroll taxes than the rich, because there is no Social Security tax on high incomes. The poorest are exempt from income tax, but do pay payroll taxes if they earn money.

In 2009, the average effective rate for all Americans is estimated to be 18.2 percent. The center estimates that if there are no changes in the law, that will rise to 23.4 percent in 2012. If the president’s proposals are all adopted, the figure that year will be 20.7 percent, with increases from 2009 for every group — those with the lowest incomes as well as those with the highest. How can that be, given that the president has promised to raise taxes only on those who make at least $250,000 a year?

Roberton Williams, a senior fellow at the Tax Policy Center, points to two reasons. First, Mr. Obama does not want to continue some special tax breaks, like a tax credit for new homeowners, that were part of the stimulus package he pushed through Congress. More important, the 2012 estimates assume a better economy, in which incomes will be higher and more people will therefore be in higher tax brackets.
By FLOYD NORRIS

Why the deficit will raise taxes

The nation's debt must be brought to heel, and doing so will require tough choices beyond spending cuts, experts say.

A $9 trillion federal deficit over 10 years may be too hard to comprehend. But this part is easy: Such unwieldy amounts of debt could have an impact on Americans' bottom line one way or the other -- if not tomorrow, then the day after.

The U.S. government has been spending a great deal more than it has been taking in, and it is on track to do so well beyond the next 10 years. It has been borrowing money to make all that spending possible and it has to pay the money back with interest. How, you ask? By borrowing more.

The solution is straightforward if unpleasant: Shy of finding a fairy willing to leave trillions under Uncle Sam's pillow, lawmakers will have to raise taxes and cut spending.

The more the country lives on a credit card, the more it makes itself beholden to the demands of its creditors -- many of which are overseas. The danger is that buyers of U.S. debt could become concerned that the country is running too high a balance. If so, they will demand higher interest rates -- thereby making the country's debt problem worse -- or they'll put their money elsewhere.

At that point, things would get ugly.

"Taxes would rise to levels that would make a Scandinavian revolt. And the government would not be able to provide anything but the most basic public services. We would no longer be a great power (or even a mediocre one), and the social safety net would evaporate," tax policy expert and Syracuse University professor Len Burman wrote in a recent op-ed cheerfully titled "Catastrophic Budget Failure."

That's why acting sooner rather than later makes sense. But acting too soon could cause its own set of problems since the economy is only beginning to lick its wounds from a punishing recession.

Economists and tax experts, no matter their ideological position, agree raising taxes when the economy is down is self-defeating.

But as the economy finds a solid footing, the hard choices will have to be made.

"We need to do this in stages at the right time," said David Walker, former U.S. comptroller general, in a CNNMoney.com video.

By Jeanne Sahadi, CNNMoney.com senior writer

U.S. Economy: GDP Contracts 1% as Recovery Approaches (Update1)

The U.S. economy took a first step toward recovering from the worst recession since the 1930s in the second quarter as companies reduced inventories, spending started to climb and profits grew.

Gross domestic product shrank at a 1 percent annual rate from April to June, less than the 1.5 percent decline projected by economists in a Bloomberg News survey, a Commerce Department report showed today in Washington. Corporate earnings rose by the most in four years, the department also said.

Government programs, including the “cash-for-clunkers” and first-time homebuyer incentives, are boosting manufacturing and housing, indicating the gain in sales that began last quarter will be sustained in the second half of the year. Another report showed unemployment may jeopardize the strength of the economic rebound.

“We’re on a pretty decent recovery path,” said Bruce Kasman, chief economist at JPMorgan Chase & Co. in New York. “There was a better mix last quarter with almost every major component of final demand being revised up and inventories being revised down. That puts us in a pretty decent position going into the third quarter.”

Stocks rose, propelled by a late rally in commodities. The Standard & Poor’s 500 Index rose 0.3 percent to close at 1,030.98. Treasury securities fell as stocks climbed, pushing up the yield on the benchmark 10-year note to 3.46 percent at 5:12 p.m. in New York from 3.44 percent late yesterday.

Profits Improve

Corporate profits, not included in the advance GDP estimate released in July, rose 5.7 percent from the first three months of the year, the biggest increase since the first quarter of 2005.

The median GDP forecast was based on a Bloomberg survey of 75 economists. Estimates ranged from declines of 1.8 percent to 0.8 percent. Today’s reading matched the government’s initial calculation issued last month and followed a 6.4 percent pace of contraction in the first three months of the year.

A separate report today showed 570,000 workers filed claims for unemployment benefits last week, down from 580,000 the previous week, the Labor Department said in Washington. While off the peak of 674,000 applications reached in the end of March, the figures compare with an average of 350,000 applications filed during the expansion that ended in December 2007.

Worst Recession

The drop in GDP was the fourth in a row, the longest contraction since quarterly records began in 1947. The world’s largest economy has shrunk 3.9 percent since last year’s second quarter, making this the deepest recession since the Great Depression.

Today’s report is the second of three estimates on second- quarter growth. The figures will be revised again in September as more information becomes available.

Consumer spending, which accounts for about 70 percent of the economy, fell at a 1 percent pace, less than anticipated, following a 0.6 percent increase in the prior quarter. Purchases were forecast to drop 1.3 percent, according to the survey median.

Spending is likely to increase this quarter. Industry data showed sales of cars and light trucks rose to an 11.2 million annual unit rate in July, the highest since September.

The “cash-for-clunkers” program, which offered buyers discounts of as much as $4,500 to trade in older cars and trucks for new, more fuel-efficient vehicles, produced almost 700,000 automobile sales before ending on Aug. 24, the Transportation Department said yesterday.

Production Gains

General Motors Co. and Chrysler Group LLC, both out of bankruptcy, are among firms set to ramp up production as government efforts lift demand.

Smaller stockpiles at companies from Wal-Mart Stores Inc. to Macy’s Inc. will contribute to a rebound in output as orders rise to stock bare shelves. Inventories dropped at a record $159.2 billion annual rate last quarter, subtracting 1.4 percentage points from growth. They dropped at a $113.9 billion pace in the first three months of the year.

Target Corp., the second-largest U.S. discount retailer, is among companies trimming costs to make up for slower sales. The Minneapolis-based company reported second-quarter profit that fell less than analysts estimated as the company avoided markdowns.

“We continue to conservatively manage our inventories to help us navigate the challenging sales environment,” Kathryn Tesija, Target’s vice president for merchandising, said in an Aug. 18 conference call.

Sales Increased

A gauge of sales that excludes inventories showed the economy grew at a 0.4 percent rate last quarter, the best performance in a year. Reports so far this month have shown government efforts to thaw credit markets and boost housing may be taking hold.

Combined sales of new and existing homes in July reached a 5.67 million annual pace, the highest level since November 2007, the month before the recession began.

A bigger jump in government spending than previously estimated helped offset the drag on growth from the slump in stockpiles. Federal, state and local expenditures climbed at a 6.4 percent annual pace, the most in more than seven years.

JPMorgan’s Kasman cautioned that unemployment claims will need to decline further to confirm his forecast that the labor market will soon improve. He acknowledged that U.S. consumers were likely to lag behind their global counterparts because of the need to repair tattered finances.

“This recovery has a lot going for it, but one thing it does not have going for it is an anticipation of a normalization for consumers,” Kasman said. “The economy will do better, but we aren’t going to have a full-bodied, strong recovery coming out of what has been a very damaging, deep recession.”

To contact the reporter on this story: Timothy R. Homan in Washington at thoman1@bloomberg.net

Network Rail plans 1,800 job cuts

Network Rail has confirmed it is planning to cut 1,800 maintenance jobs.


Network Rail maintenace staff on a line outside London
Network Rail says the jobs will go by April 2011

The company, which owns Britain's rail infrastructure, said it intended to trim the positions by April 2011, but "no final decisions have been made".

It said it hoped to avoid any compulsory redundancies. The firm currently employs a total of 33,000 people across the country.

Network Rail said the planned cuts were due to its budget for the next five years being trimmed by £4bn.

"We have a clear commitment to the British people to reduce the costs of running the railway," it said in a statement.

"Our plans to restructure our maintenance teams will improve the way we operate the network."

Network Rail added that it was now discussing its plans with staff and union representatives.

High speed call

Network Rail owns Britain's railway infrastructure, including all the tracks, signals, tunnels, bridges, level crossings and most stations.

It does not own any of the actual trains, which are operated by completely separate companies.

The company was established in 2002 when it replaced the struggling Railtrack.

Earlier this week, Network Rail proposed the building of a new £34bn high-speed railway line linking Scotland and London by 2030.

The line would serve Birmingham and Manchester, getting passengers from Glasgow to London in just two hours and 16 minutes, the rail firm said.

However, the government, which would make any final decision, said assessments of the costs and environmental issues involved needed to be carried out before it could approve any plans.

news.bbc.co.uk

Wednesday, August 26, 2009

Japanese exports continue to fall

Japanese exports slid in July at a faster annual rate than June, raising fears the effects of global stimulus measures are starting to decline.

Exports from Japan were down 36.5% last month compared with July 2008, according to the Ministry of Finance.

Slower car sales to the US, Middle East and Russia were blamed for the decline, which followed June's 35.7% fall.

The trade surplus still rose, because imports fell 40.8%, largely due to lower energy costs.

"Falls in exports have been moderating in recent months on companies' restocking efforts and government stimulus worldwide, but the July data indicate that the recovery momentum is losing steam," said Seiji Shiraishi, chief economist at HSBC Securities.

"It is questionable whether exports will continue to recover once the stimulus effect runs out."

Salaries falling


Cargo containers at port near Tokyo
Falling car sales were partly blamed for declining exports

Exports to the US fell 39.5% in July from the same month last year, which was worse than the 37.6% fall in June.

Exports to China were down 26.5%, while those going to the European Union fell 45.8%.

Gross domestic product grew 3.7% in the three months from April to June, fuelled by an improvement in exports in the period, but there have been concerns that those figures were boosted by stimulus spending and scrappage schemes.

There are also concerns that domestic demand remains weak, with average salaries falling and the unemployment rate at a six-year high of 5.4%.

BBC.

Durable Goods Orders Show Biggest Increase In 2 Years

With orders for transportation equipment showing a substantial rebound, the Commerce Department released a report on Wednesday showing that orders for durable goods increased by much more than expected in the month of July.

The report showed that new orders for durable goods jumped 4.9 percent in July following a revised 1.3 percent decrease in June. Economists had expected orders to increase by 3.2 percent compared to the 2.2 percent decrease that had been reported for the previous month.

With the rebound, which marked the third increase in the last four months, durable goods orders rose at the fastest pace since July of 2007.

Nonetheless, the growth was largely due to a sharp rise in orders for transportation equipment, which increased by 18.4 percent in July after showing a notable 12.0 percent drop in June.

The rebound in orders for transportation equipment was due in large part to a 107.2 percent increase in orders for non-defense aircraft and parts. Orders for motor vehicles and parts showed a 0.9 percent increase.

Excluding the increase in orders for transportation equipment, durable goods orders increased by a much more modest 0.8 percent in July compared to a 2.5 percent increase in June. The increase came in below economist estimates of 1.0 percent growth.
The report also showed that shipments of durable goods increased by 2.0 percent in July following a 0.7 percent increase in June. Shipments of computers and electronic products had the largest increase, surging up by 7.4 percent.

At the same time, inventories of durable goods fell for the seventh consecutive month, falling by 0.8 percent in July following a 1.5 percent decrease in June.

The Commerce Department added that orders for non-defense capital goods, excluding aircraft, which is seen as a good indicator of business spending, edged down 0.3 percent in July after increasing by 3.6 percent in the previous month.

Commenting on the data, Lindsey Piegza, economic analyst for FTN Financial said, "Despite a surge in headline orders, a closer look at the details of the report reveal business spending remains weak as we move into the third quarter."

"Corporations are still leery about the sustainability of the economic recovery and are timid in reopening the spending spigots," Piegza added.

Next Wednesday, the Commerce Department is scheduled to release its July report on factory orders, which include orders for durable goods as well as orders for non-durable goods.

by RTT Staff Writer

For comments and feedback: contact editorial@rttnews.com

The Wall Street-Main Street Paradox

These days, many folks are feeling justifiably befuddled, as the contrast between Wall Street and Main Street is perhaps as striking a divergence as what was seen before the 2008 Credit Crisis bust. To be sure, the stock market continues to perform well, and at least on the surface the economic headlines appear to have reached a plateau. Yet below the surface the outlook for 2010 is taking on a grimmer and grimmer profile. Going back to December of 2008, I wrote a piece entitled “Tracking the “Official” Recession.”

I stated that the odds would be high that the current ‘great recession’ would take the shape of a “W”, implying a “Double Dip” contraction. Back then, I stated,

“In my view, a more accurate forecast might suggest that a “35 to 40” month economic contraction makes more sense, implying that the present period of great financial turmult may not end until early 2011. Yet, in contemplating these figures, a repeat of the 1980 to 1982 scenario in my view is starting to make the most sense. This is the so called “Double-Dip” recession outcome, where we may see an important economic “statistical low” in the early portion of 2009 (say April, May 2009), followed by a lengthy statistical rebound (perhaps 12 months – i.e. May 2010), followed in turn by a second, even more strongly declining contraction phase beginning in the latter half of 2010. It would not surprise me to see that second phase last a good 20 months in its own right implying that the final contraction bottom may not be seen before early 2012.”

Of course as it happened, the economic data began to turn up in March – April of this year, and has been on an understated bounce over the last few months. In today’s headlines, we learned that Consumer Confidence as tracked by the conference improved to a reading of 54.1 in August, up from a revised reading of 47.40 in July. Within the Consumer Confidence report, the Present Situation Index increased to a reading of 24.90 in August, up from 23.30 in July. At the same time, the Consumer Expectations Index rose to 73.50 in August, up from 63.40 in July. In the chart below, I show the steady increase in the Forward Expectation chart along with the 12 month Rate of Change in Forward Expectations (see lower clip for ROC). At present, I find that their remains a lot of upside momentum behind the current resurgence in the consumer outlook, which in my view implies that the current trend is likely to be maintained for another two to three months. In fact, in my view, the Forward Expectations component -- the leading component of the survey -- is likely to rise toward a value in the 88 to 96 range (see little dashed box) before the current advance is complete. Once Forward Expectations have reached a value in that zone, I believe things will be in the neighborhood from which point a renewed downside contraction may emerge.

0825.01

Above: Consumer Confidence Forward Expectations (top clip) and Rate of Change on Expectations lower clip.

Elsewhere, the Case-Shiller Index for June showed that the prices for single family homes rose a non-seasonally adjusted 1.40%, the second increase after falling every month for the last three years. In addition, the Federal Housing Finance Agency reported that its index of home prices fell .7% in the second quarter, with prices down 6.10% from the prior year. Like the economy as a whole, housing seems to be trying to find a temporary plateau but has an overall forward looking outlook that is still quite bearish. Not only are home inventories as reported still at record levels, but in many markets banks are holding REO properties off the market in a huge shadow inventory that will likely continue to put downside pressure on housing for some time to come. In addition, I strongly believe that long term interest rates are near another important low, and that upside pressure on long term rates will depress housing in 2010. Thus, while we remain on track for a positive Q3 GDP report as “Cash for Clunkers” will likely have a substantial one off positive affect on sales, the odds remain very high that as 2009 draws to a close, the early going in 2010 will see the return of recession. As a result, investors need to remain very nimble and cannot take their eyes off the stock market charts. This is not an investors “Buy and Hold” market; it is a traders market that needs to be evaluated at least once a day.

As I see it, the overall trend for the equity market continues to remain positive with prices underpinned by a strong under current of positive momentum. Normally, this kind of momentum would take several weeks at least to dwindle down to the point where a larger, more powerful correction could take hold. As can be seen in the chart below, as the S&P has been moving steadily higher, the GST Advance-Decline Line for Operating Companies has been moving in 100% lockstep. That means that the underlying trend remains healthy.

0825.02
Above: S&P 500 with GST Cumulative Advance-Decline Line (Operating Companies Only)

In addition to the positive action in the A/D Line, the McClellan Summation Index for the US equity market is also in very strongly positive territory. Last night the Summation Index ended at a reading of +7,348.30, and that is only a few points down from a recent peak at +7,626.78 seen on August 13th, 2009. Looking back at prior history when the Summation Index is over +4,000 it is usually a sign of strength, with readings above 7,000 denoting unusually strong climates. Notice that going back on the chart we saw a reading of +7730.19 back on June 17th, 2003. Some analysts would go so far as to claim that these kinds of readings always denote a bull market condition. On that point, I would defer and simply make the case that they almost always denote a market that is a reasonable distance in terms of time (i.e. number of weeks) from an important high. To this end, with the Summation Index at such lofty levels I am less concerned about the approaching seasonally negative September and October time periods. In fact I would actually argue that this year, these months have a good chance at being positive months with the equity market trend likely to begin deteriorating in November, and then potentially really deteriorating from December on. In my view 2010 will be another major bear market year, and I would not be the least bit surprised to see the equity markets wipe out the entirety of this year's advance (660 to 1150-1200(?)) and possibly even make new multi-year lows below 660 on the S&P.

0825.03
Above: tight shot on the McClellan Summation Index

0825.04
Above: Long term view of Summation Index with other high momentum values in 97-98.

0825.05
Above: 20 day Oscillator of Advances and Decline.

But for now, the Return of the Bear will have to wait as the overall chart configuration for the stock market remains positive. Notice on the chart above that over the last few months the 20 day Oscillator of Advances less Declines has been making steadily higher highs, essentially confirming the underlying trend in the S&P. Now, I do believe that as the markets move into late September/October, the trend will begin to thin out and fewer sectors will participate, but I have not reached that point as this time. Another gauge which helps us keep an eye on the current psychology of the market is the Relative Strength Ratio of Consumer Discretionary to Consumer Staples. In my work, I convert this to a medium term trend oscillator which shows that market psychology is still positive as long as the oscillator is above zero. At the moment, the readings remain at reasonably healthy levels, which again suggests that the underlying uptrend probably has further to go in the weeks ahead. On a very short term basis there is support for the S&P at 1007 to 1010, and we could see a small 5 to 7 day correction down to those levels, but that would fall under the header of a minor reaction and should lead to another buyable low.

0825.06

Above: Relative Strength Ratio of Consumer Discretionary to Consumer Staples, Oscillator is still in positive territory above zero.

Other gauges which continue to trend toward optimism are a swath of sentiment gauges, including the Put-to-Call Ratio, the VIX Index and the Gold to Goldman Ratio. Importantly, sentiment indicators tend to give false signals in the middle phases of a strong advance. In that regard my emphasis at the moment would be more on trend following and breadth-momentum gauges; until these really begin to fall off, the sentiment group is likely to be ‘too early’. For now, the Put Call Ratio is still not down to its lower band, and still not down to the low end of the range of the last few years. Similarly, VIX is trending down but will probably revisit last year's low readings in the 18 to 20 range before this advance has peaked. We also like to watch the Ratio of Physical Gold to Goldman Sachs (GS) as a crisis-optimism proxy. When the atmosphere is starting to turn hostile, Gold begins to out-perform Goldman, and when confidence is gaining the upper hand, money runs at Goldman Sachs and steps back a bit from Gold. In this occasion, that may be a bit tricky as we expect the Gold price to turn in a strong second half on the back of a weaker Dollar, but nevertheless, for now at least, Goldman Sachs is going up at a faster clip than gold, and so we glean a positive environmental signal from this Ratio which is confirming the direction of the VIX.

0825.07
Above: The Put to Call Ratio

0825.08
Above: upper – Gold to Goldman Ratio and lower – the VIX Index

Finally, investors should be anticipating some degree of further rotation in the stock market with Healthcare possibly emerging as a more solid performer in Q3 and Q4. In the chart below I show the Relative Strength of Healthcare versus Technology where we see that Healthcare is beginning to outperform. This ties in with a piece I did a few weeks back, when I featured Managed Care Stocks which have done quite nicely since I wrote about them, and which still look to be emerging from a major double bottom base.

0825.09
Above: GST Healthcare Index versus Technology Stocks

0825.10
Above: GST Managed Care Index

Where the Manager Care sector is concerned, my focus would be exclusively on the idea of buying pull backs and reactions on the order of 3% to 5% if and when they develop. Overall, volume in the sector continues to act very well, and with the recent developments in Washington, it is becoming more clear that, as I suspected, this sector will not be harmed that much, if at all, by any Obamacare legislation should such a plan even make it to fruition.

0825.11
Above: Cumulative Up to Down Volume Healthcare Stocks.

Bottom Line: Investors putting money into the stock market at this relatively late stage of the rally need to understand that they must be nimble and must be watching their stocks at all times. While the rally likely continues to have a few more weeks of life and could press toward 1100-1200 as the year wears on, ultimately, we are likely dealing with a very large bear market rally that will be followed by a much more challenging market in 2010. While things on Wall Street are momentarily taking on a better spin (with easy Q4 comps directly ahead), on Mainstreet unemployment remains very high and is unlikely to recover in any meaningful way. Going forward, we note that as the stock market approaches the early phases of 2010, (especially the pre-announcement of Q1 EPS in March) analysts will start looking at very tough potential EPS comparisons, and as April 2010 approaches (and actual announcements begin), we will likely see a swath of conference calls showing a dramatic lack of top line sales growth. At that point life in the equity market will start becoming a whole lot less pleasant. At the moment, the sun is out, and most sectors are moving higher.

That’s all for now,
www.financialsense.com

Monday, August 24, 2009

Federal deficits: $9 trillion and counting

The White House and the Congressional Budget Office will offer updates on their 10-year federal deficit estimates, as well as their economic outlooks.


NEW YORK (CNNMoney.com) -- In just over a month, the federal government's fiscal year will draw to a close, leaving in its wake one of the biggest annual deficits in U.S. history -- and a forecast of more record debt to come.

Just how much more will be the question on Tuesday.

The Congressional Budget Office and the White House Office of Management and Budget are set to release separate updates of their 10-year deficit estimates, along with updates on their economic outlooks.

The agencies' previous estimates -- based on the president's proposed 2010 budget -- were about $2 trillion apart.

The CBO, which serves as Congress' official scorekeeper, had the higher estimate: $9.14 trillion over 10 years or 5.2% of gross domestic product.

By comparison, the Obama administration's budget office forecast a $7.11 trillion deficit or 4% of GDP.

The White House's economic estimates were seen by many as too optimistic. For instance, the administration estimated that unemployment would hit a peak of 8.1% this year. Actual unemployment numbers have already surpassed that level -- hitting 9.4% in July. And many economists expect the number to reach 10% before too long.

Last week, White House officials said their new 10-year deficit forecast will be in the neighborhood of $9 trillion, in part because Uncle Sam is pulling down less tax revenue than expected. That would bring it more in line with the CBO's previous forecast.

Analysts say the best-case scenario on Tuesday would be if the CBO's updated deficit forecast stays very much in line with its earlier $9 trillion estimate.

That's because foreign investors who buy U.S. debt have already factored in that amount.

"If [the CBO] numbers come in higher, that would be cause for concern," said Sean West, U.S. policy analyst at the Eurasia Group, a political risk research firm.

The concern, of course, is that foreign governments and other foreign investors could demand higher interest rates or stop buying as much U.S. debt.

One mitigating factor -- in the near-term anyway -- is the rapid rise in the U.S. savings rate over the past year. That's because banks can make money by investing savers' deposits in U.S. Treasurys, which pay more than what the banks have to pay customers on deposits.

"Rising U.S. savings will offset the need to find foreign investors," said Ross Schaap, Eurasia's director of comparative analytics.

But even domestically financed deficits come at a cost if they grow too large for too long.

"Deficits will gradually divert capital from productive domestic uses, through a rise in interest rates. This diversion reduces the amount of capital available to U.S. workers, lowering their wages and hence their living standards," deficit experts Alan J. Auerbach and William G. Gale wrote in a CNNMoney.com commentary. "If our deficits are financed from abroad, interest rates may not rise as much, but interest payments on these deficits will flow back abroad."

Where's the exit?

The deficit forecasts on Tuesday will underline the pressures facing President Obama in a weak economy.

It may make political sense to declare that the majority of Americans will not see their taxes go up, as Obama has done repeatedly, West said. But the administration eventually will have to come up with a sufficient exit strategy from the ballooning levels of federal debt, he noted.

That's not to say the administration has been silent on the issue. To the contrary, the White House has pushed for pay-as-you-go rules that would require Congress to pay for spending increases or new tax cuts. It has also proposed $17 billion worth of spending cuts.

Most notably, Obama has been pushing for health care reform to help bring the deficit in line since runaway health care costs are a major problem.

At the same time, the White House has said it would exempt from pay-go policies some of its priciest proposals, such as extending the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts for most households. And the course of health care reform is anything but a straight line to lower costs, no matter whose proposal takes top spot at the end of the day.

money.cnn.com

Bank of America defends Merrill bonuses

Bank of America Corp mounted an aggressive defense of Merrill Lynch & Co's decision to award some $3.6 billion of bonuses last

year, as it tries to convince a federal judge to approve a settlement with the US Securities and Exchange Commission over its disclosures.

In a Monday filing with Manhattan federal court, the largest US bank said it was "widely understood" from Merrill's public disclosures and media reports that Merrill would award billions of dollars of year-end bonuses, despite a full-year loss that would reach $27.6 billion. Bank of America also said it made "no false or misleading statement or omission" in its proxy statement distributed to shareholders who voted on the bank's acquisition of Merrill, which closed on Jan 1.

"The intention of Merrill Lynch & Co Inc to pay incentive compensation for 2008 was disclosed and was part of the 'total mix' of information available to shareholders," the bank said. Bank of America had agreed on Aug 3 to pay $33 million to resolve an SEC civil lawsuit saying the Charlotte, North Carolina-based bank misled shareholders by not disclosing it had authorized up to $5.8 billion of bonuses at Merrill.

US District Judge Jed Rakoff, however, rejected the settlement, demanding many more details about who knew what and when about the bonuses, including the decision not to reveal the payouts before the merger closed. The bonuses have been the focus of Congressional hearings and a probe by New York Attorney General Andrew Cuomo.

At a hearing on Aug. 10, Rakoff said the $33 million settlement seemed to be "lacking in transparency" and "strangely askew," and might not prove "remotely reasonable" if the SEC were right that the bank lied about the bonuses. Rakoff said he could not reconcile the SEC's position that Bank of America "effectively lied" to shareholders with its decision not to force the bank to admit wrongdoing.

Noting that the government pumped $45 billion into Bank of America from the federal bank bailout plan, Rakoff said that "one might infer that public money was used, in effect, to pay the bonuses." The SEC is expected on Monday to file its own papers regarding the settlement. It is unclear whether Rakoff will approve the settlement or seek to modify it.

Bank of America shares were up 4 cents at $17.50 in afternoon trading on the New York Stock Exchange. The case is SEC v Bank of America Corp, US District Court, Southern District of New York (Manhattan), No 09-6829.
economictimes.indiatimes.com

Recession in Britain 'at an end'

Confidence among business professionals has surged, suggesting the recession is at an end, a survey has said.

The Institute of Chartered Accountants' index of business confidence rose to 4.8 at the end of June, from -28.2 in March, the biggest rise for two years.

However, chief executive Michael Izza warned against "underestimating" the challenges ahead for businesses.

The institute predicts the UK economy will grow by 0.5% in the third quarter of 2009.

Its forecast comes after the economy shrank by 0.8% in the second quarter of the year.

More than 1,000 chartered accountants were surveyed across England, Wales and Scotland.

Investor confidence about the UK economy also appears to be growing, with the UK's main FTSE 100 share index ending Monday trading at a 10-month high of 4,896, up 0.9% on the day.

More optimism

"This quarter's Business Confidence Monitor suggests that the UK recession is at an end," said Mr Izza.

Many are now more optimistic that the global recession is ending.

Japan, France and Germany have all recently emerged from recession in the second quarter between April and June, as have Asian economies like Thailand and Hong Kong.

US Federal Reserve chairman Ben Bernanke has also said that the US, the world's largest economy, is approaching recovery.

While initial figures showed that neither the US or UK grew in the second quarter, many expect economic output to return to positive territory in the three months to September.

"The considerable stimulus from the easing of monetary and fiscal policy and the past depreciation of sterling should lead to a recovery in economic activity," the Bank of England said earlier this month.

'Challenge'

The confidence survey said that 41% of senior professionals were more confident about their business prospects in the next year, but only 6% were much more confident, indicating that some caution remains.

Canary Wharf
The banking sector saw a big rise in confidence

"While there is no doubt that the UK economy is on its way to recovery, we shouldn't underestimate the challenges ahead for businesses," said Mr Izza.

IT was the most optimistic sector, followed by banking, finance and insurance. The institute said the banking sector in particular had shown "a remarkable upturn given the turmoil of the last two years".

The least confident professions were health and education, as fears of cuts in the public sector grow.

Reservations

Policymakers have been wary of stoking expectations that the UK's economic woes are over.

"The pace of recovery over the next few years is highly uncertain," said Bank Governor Mervyn King.

The Bank surprised the financial markets by injecting £50bn of new money into the economy earlier this month, more than the £25bn that had been expected.

The move, which took the total to £175bn, is viewed as a sign of how divided the Bank committee members that set interests rates are over the recovery in the UK economy.

In addition, the number of jobless in the UK is now at its highest level since 1995, with 2.4 million people out of work.

GDP charts
news.bbc.co.uk

Calls to reopen CIA abuse cases

economics
The US justice department is calling for some dozen prisoner abuse cases to be reopened, the New York Times says.

The recommendation could lead to the prosecution of CIA employees and contractors over the treatment of terrorism suspects, the newspaper says.

The call comes as justice officials are set to disclose previously censored parts of a report into detainee abuse.

These show how electric drills and mock executions were used by CIA agents to elicit information, US media say.

A heavily censored version of the 2004 internal Central Intelligence Agency (CIA) report was released last year but in an almost meaningless form because so much remained classified, the BBC's Daniel Sandford reports from Washington.

A federal judge ordered more details to be released on Monday, after a legal challenge by the American Civil Liberties Union (Aclu).
According to US media, the report by the CIA's inspector general details how a gun and an electric drill were brought into an interrogation session of suspected USS Cole bomber and alleged al-Qaeda commander Rahim al-Nashiri in a bid to frighten him.

In another case, a gun was fired in another room to lead a detainee to think another suspect had been killed.

The US has banned harsh interrogation methods, including death threats.

Even under the Bush administration's controversial interpretation of the law, causing "severe mental pain" by the "threat of imminent death" was considered illegal.

Criminal inquiry

The call for the reopening of the prisoner abuse cases - mainly in Iraq and Afghanistan - was made by the US department of justice's ethics office, the New York Times reported.

The cases account for about half of those that were referred to the justice department by the CIA's inspector general but which were later closed.

A CIA spokesman told the New York Times that the advice to reopen closed cases had not been sent to the agency.

"Decisions on whether or not to pursue action in court were made after careful consideration by career prosecutors at the justice department. The CIA itself brought these matters - facts and allegations alike - to the department's attention," said the spokesman, Paul Gimigliano.

The recommendations to review some cases, which would reverse Bush administration policy, have been sent to US Attorney General Eric Holder.

He is set to announce soon whether he will appoint a prosecutor to investigate alleged abuse by CIA agents.

It is expected that he will go ahead with a new criminal inquiry.

Such a decision would pose problems for the CIA. It would also have political ramifications given President Barack Obama's desire to leave questions over the Bush administration's interrogation practices in the past, correspondents say.

In another development, Mr Obama has approved the creation of a new unit to question key terrorism suspects, the Washington Post reported.

The unit, called the High-Value Detainee Interrogation Group, is to be composed of experts from several intelligence and law enforcement agencies.

It will be housed at the FBI but will be overseen by the national Security Council, giving the White House direct oversight, the paper reports.

Space by Balloon - Bang Goes the Theory Episode 4


From Youtobe

Sunday, August 23, 2009

Oil price touches high for 2009

economics

The price of oil has hit its highest level of the year, boosted by sharp rises in Chinese stocks and rising shares on Wall Street.

The price of US crude rose to $74.15 a barrel before settling at $73.89, a gain of 98 cents. London Brent was up 86 cents at $74.19.

The oil price hit $147 a barrel last July and fell below $74 last October, a level it has not breached since.

Worldwide oil prices have been extremely volatile this year.

Prices have been affected as much by sentiment as by fundamentals of demand and supply.

Ben Bernanke, the chairman of the Federal Reserve, said that prospects for a return to growth in the near term appeared good in the US and abroad.

US shares traded higher - with the Dow Jones index rising 1.7% to 9,506 - after Mr Bernanke's speech and on better-than-expected figures for sales of existing homes.

Sales rose by 7.2% in July to an annual rate of 5.24 million homes.

"The significant rise in the oil price in the first half of the year is due in large part to a recovery in investment by financial investors," said Eugen Weinberg at Commerzbank.

news.bbc.co.uk